Like what you've read?

On Line Opinion is the only Australian site where you get all sides of the story. We don't
charge, but we need your support. Here�s how you can help.

  • Advertise

    We have a monthly audience of 70,000 and advertising packages from $200 a month.

  • Volunteer

    We always need commissioning editors and sub-editors.

  • Contribute

    Got something to say? Submit an essay.


 The National Forum   Donate   Your Account   On Line Opinion   Forum   Blogs   Polling   About   
On Line Opinion logo ON LINE OPINION - Australia's e-journal of social and political debate

Subscribe!
Subscribe





On Line Opinion is a not-for-profit publication and relies on the generosity of its sponsors, editors and contributors. If you would like to help, contact us.
___________

Syndicate
RSS/XML


RSS 2.0

The downside of individualised social services

By Peter Gibilisco - posted Tuesday, 30 October 2007


The dominant political agenda is ignorant of the belief that people cannot get ahead in life on their own, proclaiming the many positive actions that individualism can supply, all dressed in neo-liberal political rhetoric.  This is despite the fact that we are only human, and our behaviours and attitudes are formed by our environment.  In most cases, despite the independence that an individual may have, or how they may struggle to acquire it, we are social creatures and we have to work together in order to help each other.  As humans, most of us are social animals and therefore require society, contrary to the individual rhetoric of the dominant neo-liberal political agenda, shown, for example, in this quote by a figurehead of that agenda, Margaret Thatcher: “there is no such thing as society, there are individual[s]..…

The world-wide shift in support services for people with disabilities first took place in the 1980s, implementing a marketised style of reform to the disability sector.  This involves the more efficient delivery of support services for people with disabilities, based on calculations and therefore helping pave the way for budget surpluses.  In the 1990s, support services reforms to disability sectors around the world were driven by neo-liberal and third way political ideologies, which favoured the market and a minimal government approach that can be identified with the strategy of survival of the fittest.

This is highlighted by the political rhetoric of today, which can be identified by the rhetoric of individualized support services that are promised by disability services (idiosyncratic name: disability services); that is, created by the dominant neo-liberal political environments, and further integrated into both major parties in Australia (Federal, State, and Local government). For example, in a recent On-Line-Opinion article I stated:

Advertisement

"despite its rhetoric and references to social inclusion and social rights, the DHS approach to the State Disability Plan is a social policy that identifies the social supports required by those who need them as burdensome to a marketised economy, and to the ultimate goals of delivering budgetary surpluses. Its rationale to reduce social spending, does not result in the achievement of human rights and social justice, but an increase in individual human suffering and social exclusion."

These views of mine have been applauded and shared by the majority of people with disabilities, who have come across my opinions.

The individualised rhetoric of neo-liberal discourse is criticized by Hugh Stretton and Lionel Orchard, who question the ability of individually based social services to drive effective public policy.  Believing that if the policies are derived, one by one, from the citizens’ voices, one issue after another, the social initiative will stray from its original intentions.   As Stretton and Orchard point out in Public Goods, Public Enterprise, Public Choice: Theoretical Foundations of the Contemporary Attack on Government (1994):

Advertisement

“How could individual preferences in practice produce workable public policies? …The technical planning, budgeting and coordination which now strain the resources of elaborative public services would have to be designed instead by each voter as she registered her vote”.

This prompts the question: is the promotion of individualised social services just another social dilemma?, as it provides a paradox in its ability to practically provide services. This highlights some of the complexities that are involved when they reform traditionally collective social policies, with their standardised, systematic and rhetorical individualised approach.

Direct payments

Such reform allows the state, in theory, to enjoy the efficiency and budgetary savings that are provided by the market provision of support services to people with disabilities.  In the USA and Europe, the direction for service provision for people with disabilities can vary from country to country, state to state, according to regulations or political economic agendas.  But in general, the system of direct payments allows the person with a disability, or his or her person of choice, to be the employer of personal care services.  This style of reform cuts back on bureaucratic administration.  This, in theory, is believed to give people with disabilities more freedom of choice concerning service provision.

It is of interest to acknowledge that several European countries and the USA have implemented a range of long-term care programs, such as direct payments, which, in theory, are intended to promote independent living options for many years to come.  Many of these programs of support services provide for cash payments to personal carers, including, in certain countries only, family members of the person with a disability, to allow direct payment for appropriate care.

Government budgetary savings on administration costs for the provision of care for people with disabilities have already and will be appreciated by many Western political leaders.  This points out the probability that by cutting out the administration costs and putting the administrative responsibilities into the hands of the users it is said to help provide a form of empowerment to its users, who are people with disabilities.

To me, as a pragmatic disability scholar, this highlights that the system of direct payments could be shown to be much more effective with the use of co-operatives, that is, in a model of direct payments in which service users can choose who their intermediary is; a co-operative of choice.   Consequently, if a group of people wanted to establish a co-operative, and if that co-operative had a value-added approach, it would thrive and be able to support more people with disabilities.

For example co-operatives would undertake a procedure, where public funds that are allocated to pay for support services, those allocated to the management of disabilities, would be paid directly to administer and supply adequate care for people with disabilities.  Those funds would be controlled by the users, rather than by bureaucrats.  This favourably compares with the old style and with the proposed new style of service provision to people with disabilities.  In the old style a co-operative would have a bureaucrat systematically match a person’s disability with the amount of funds that are made available.  But the new style, in theory, provides for a system where a co-operative calls the shots, rather than bureaucrats.

The following example illustrates the argument.  If over the next five years there are 2,000 people with disabilities in need of support through personal care for various reasons related to their disabilities.  Those allocated funds would be pooled and a co-operative would invest them in a way that would be productive and match with the users of direct payments.  As a result, decision making for the process of direct payments would be made through a theoretical collective approach defined by a co-operative of people who the user of direct payments chooses.

This approach to the strategy of the service provision for people with disabilities provides for a win-win partnership, as people with disabilities and their co-operatives could also develop sustainable business relationships with private companies that supply, for example, mobility aids to people with disabilities.  This form of strategic business plan could help with the provision of ongoing support to people with disabilities.  This strategic and creative use of public money is controlled by the users through their co-operatives, giving a form of personal empowerment to people with disabilities.

However, without the objective administration process supplied by the collective allocation of direct payments, in practice this would be a primary target for the misallocation of public funds.  For example, a person with a disability or trustee, is the recipient of $30,000 to supply care needs for the next six months.  Lacking the administrative skills and diligence of the public service, and like most humans, will indulge themselves in a small spending spree, but in this case probably on disability equipment, regardless of the individual’s care needs.  I understand this program entails comprehensive training, but upfront, the long term need for care is superseded by the human temptation to commit economically self-interested actions.

So if bad decisions are made then care time has to be shortened and carers have to share the blame for the poor administration of funds. Because of the misallocation of funds, a carer's time may have to be cut from 4 to 2 ½ hours to compensate the error by the collective's office bearer, even when a personal administrative error is made. It is a social system of shared responsibility.

To give a small example, such an action is a constant occurrence in the Continence Aids Assistance Scheme, where a person with a disability is given $480 a year for the purchase of continence aids, in many cases this is allocated mainly for the purchase of enemas.  In such a situation the purchaser, myself on many occasions, is easily side tracked and spends too much of the given monies on non-essential aids, leaving a shortfall for the purchase of essential items. So what we are also dealing with here is a way of support that also helps regulate direct payments, since regulation also costs money and current governments do not see such support as an investment (as they should) but as a diversion of funds from a budget surplus.

In conclusion, I have briefly outlined some of my criticisms within the disability sector of the largely rhetorical and dominant political ideology known as individualism.   I have subsequently outlined how the flaws of gatekeeping and regulation may be assisted by independently selected co -operatives.

  1. Pages:
  2. 1
  3. 2
  4. All

This article was first presented as a seminar at the National Disability Services conference.



Discuss in our Forums

See what other readers are saying about this article!

Click here to read & post comments.

7 posts so far.

Share this:
reddit this reddit thisbookmark with del.icio.us Del.icio.usdigg thisseed newsvineSeed NewsvineStumbleUpon StumbleUponsubmit to propellerkwoff it

About the Author

Peter Gibilisco was diagnosed with the progressive neurological condition called Friedreich's Ataxia, at age 14. The disability has made his life painful and challenging. He rocks the boat substantially in the formation of needed attributes to succeed in life. For example, he successfully completed a PhD at the University of Melbourne, this was achieved late into the disability's progression. However, he still performs research with the university, as an honorary fellow. Please read about his new book The Politics of Disability.

Other articles by this Author

All articles by Peter Gibilisco

Creative Commons LicenseThis work is licensed under a Creative Commons License.

Photo of Peter Gibilisco
Article Tools
Comment 7 comments
Print Printable version
Subscribe Subscribe
Email Email a friend
Advertisement

About Us Search Discuss Feedback Legals Privacy