Like what you've read?

On Line Opinion is the only Australian site where you get all sides of the story. We don't
charge, but we need your support. Here�s how you can help.

  • Advertise

    We have a monthly audience of 70,000 and advertising packages from $200 a month.

  • Volunteer

    We always need commissioning editors and sub-editors.

  • Contribute

    Got something to say? Submit an essay.


 The National Forum   Donate   Your Account   On Line Opinion   Forum   Blogs   Polling   About   
On Line Opinion logo ON LINE OPINION - Australia's e-journal of social and political debate

Subscribe!
Subscribe





On Line Opinion is a not-for-profit publication and relies on the generosity of its sponsors, editors and contributors. If you would like to help, contact us.
___________

Syndicate
RSS/XML


RSS 2.0

What’s wrong with single-member electorates - Part 2

By Bogey Musidlak - posted Friday, 15 March 2002


Party boxes were introduced in the 1983 overhaul of the Commonwealth Electoral Act, ostensibly as a short-cut way of recording a formal vote, and have spread to other jurisdictions. The alternative of having to mark nearly all the squares individually otherwise continues to be an unfair imposition on voters. The result has been a concentration of power in the hands of those making preference deals straight after nominations close, and a proliferation of party groups in New South Wales and South Australian Legislative Council elections where state-wide seats can be won with a relatively small proportion of the votes.

Voters marking party boxes usually have no idea what is to be made of their indicated support. When those influential within Grey Power and the Citizens’ Electoral Councils Group succeeded in blackballing Liberal Chris Puplick in NSW in 1990, most of their groups’ supporters would have been greatly surprised if they ever discovered that their votes made the difference between two or three Labor Senators being elected. At the Western Australian Legislative Council elections of 2001, One Nation supporters marking the party box in two non-metropolitan regions unwittingly handed the balance of power to the Greens, who were placed before the Liberals on those registered how-to-vote tickets.

A straightforward way of avoiding these induced problems would have been to make it easy for all voters to record a formal vote. For instance, in the Australian Capital Territory's Hare-Clark system where the absence of party boxes has been entrenched, voters are encouraged to mark at least as many preferences as there are vacancies, but do not lose their vote if they fail to do so.

Advertisement

Where does that leave us?

Hare-Clark as best practice

If we really want to clean up the image of politics, first we should strive for a system where there are no safe seats at all as that will force anyone with an intention of being in politics for some time to pay attention to what’s important for constituents.

Having an effective vote, one that contributes to the election of one or more candidates, has the Parliament looking much more like what the people indicate they want in each region. It also sparks more interest in politics because individual outcomes aren’t a foregone conclusion.

Once you have seven or nine vacancies in an electorate (12.5 per cent and 10 per cent respectively is enough to secure election), a shift of even 2 or 3 per cent in support is quite likely to change representation. No area can be taken for granted or written off as a lost cause, and there are incentives to build further support to win more seats.

Geographical considerations may point to the inclusion of five-member electorates even though over 16 per cent of the vote could be wasted and major parties might feel confident of winning two seats in most circumstances. While much larger numbers of vacancies would reduce vote wastage, ballot-papers can become unwieldy if a hundred or more candidates nominate.

Advertisement

The best model available is the Hare-Clark system in use in Tasmania since 1909, and adopted at plebiscite and then entrenched in the Australian Capital Territory during the 1990s.

Safe seats have been eliminated through the introduction of Robson Rotation. Names are rotated within party columns on ballot-papers so that the vote for the party gets shared out and those with greatest explicit voter support get elected. This has forced candidates to do much more doorknocking and to make themselves more accessible to voters over a period of time. Being able to generate some publicity while in the Assembly or during the campaign period has been shown to be no guarantee of continued success.

A further highlight leading to more choice for voters on election day is the use of count-back of the votes for a vacating candidate to determine the replacement. This maintains voter influence over the composition of the Parliament at all times without risking compromising proportional representation through by-elections (as occurs in Eire): it will work satisfactorily without delay in all circumstances, unlike the Senate approach of party nomination where possible, under which as many as one in five incumbents has not been elected by the people.

  1. Pages:
  2. 1
  3. 2
  4. Page 3
  5. All

This is part two of Bogey Musidlak's commentary. In part one he discussed the problems with Australia's current system of representative democracy.



Discuss in our Forums

See what other readers are saying about this article!

Click here to read & post comments.

Share this:
reddit this reddit thisbookmark with del.icio.us Del.icio.usdigg thisseed newsvineSeed NewsvineStumbleUpon StumbleUponsubmit to propellerkwoff it

About the Author

Bogey Musidlak is President of the Proportional Representation Society of Australia.

Other articles by this Author

All articles by Bogey Musidlak
Related Links
Proportional Representation Society
Article Tools
Comment Comments
Print Printable version
Subscribe Subscribe
Email Email a friend
Advertisement

About Us Search Discuss Feedback Legals Privacy