Like what you've read?

On Line Opinion is the only Australian site where you get all sides of the story. We don't
charge, but we need your support. Here�s how you can help.

  • Advertise

    We have a monthly audience of 70,000 and advertising packages from $200 a month.

  • Volunteer

    We always need commissioning editors and sub-editors.

  • Contribute

    Got something to say? Submit an essay.


 The National Forum   Donate   Your Account   On Line Opinion   Forum   Blogs   Polling   About   
On Line Opinion logo ON LINE OPINION - Australia's e-journal of social and political debate

Subscribe!
Subscribe





On Line Opinion is a not-for-profit publication and relies on the generosity of its sponsors, editors and contributors. If you would like to help, contact us.
___________

Syndicate
RSS/XML


RSS 2.0

Free trade: offering the best value to consumers and producers

By Alan Moran - posted Friday, 16 September 2011


It is therefore possible for a country to embark on a growth momentum in spite of protectionist restraint on imports. But in all such cases the protection has co-existed with privatisation, deregulation and increased levels of domestic savings to fuel productive investment. Those efficiency improvements have more than compensated for the adverse effects of protectionist policies.

And the respective outcomes in Singapore and Hong Kong indicate that the latter's free trade policy has achieved similar stellar growth while seeing less income allocated to savings. In other words, it would appear that a more liberal trade policy allowed Hong Kong both to have and to eat more of its cake.

The point about free trade is that it provides the cheapest goods and services to the consumer. This may entail importing from countries that follow practices that we ourselves reject. Thus some countries have more relaxed laws than us on matters like child labour. We can urge those countries to change such laws but the appropriate standards are matters of judgement. After all, child labour is common on farms in Australia, some kids sell lemonade at charity stands and 30 years ago there were plenty of 14 year olds in the Australian workforce.

Advertisement

Similarly, some countries' workplace safety standards are sometimes cited as a reason why we should reject their imports. Safety standards tend to be highest in the more affluent countries and in the end reflect the willingness of the worker to accept greater risk as a consequence.

Importantly, it is not up to us to pick and choose which imports we might allow on grounds of labour laws and so on, since to do so would require us to develop a vast new apparatus to determine what countries goods and services will be allowed.

It may well make sense to refuse some imports on quarantine grounds but, as already noted, quarantine provisions are often an excuse to protect domestic producers, thereby preventing domestic consumers from benefitting from the cheapest suppliers. At the same time the protectionist policy means maintaining land, labour and capital in activities that produce less value than if they were to be shifted to areas of greater competitiveness.

Keeping Australian and World Markets Open

World trade negotiations have focussed on offering and accepting concessions in reducing domestic barriers to entry. Although such mechanisms may have been useful in bringing political acceptance for trade liberalisation (and a general global reduction in barriers to trade, offers gains in excess of a unilateral reduction), we don't actually need reciprocity to make gains.

If some countries place barriers to getting the cheapest goods they are willingly accepting a diminution of their real income levels. That can rarely be in their interests.

Advertisement

The liberalisation of trade over the past sixty years has been crucial to higher living standards in Australia and elsewhere. Reversing that trend would see a relative and perhaps absolute fall in living standards.

A major frontier left behind in trade liberalisation is agriculture. Australia could gain considerably from the rapid income growth in China and India, which is likely to see a considerable expansion in demand for higher protein and fat foods.

Though geographically well placed to benefit from this, Australian policy directions in recent years detract from this potential. Disallowing water storages (and reducing existing water rights held by farmers), locking up vast tracts of land in northern Australia and arbitrary decisions like that on live cattle exports have reduced the attraction of farm investment.

A deregulatory approach is necessary as well as continued resistance to backsliding on protectionism to allow labour and capital to be used more remuneratively is essential if the prospects are to be realised.

  1. Pages:
  2. 1
  3. Page 2
  4. All

Article edited by Kali Goldstone.
If you'd like to be a volunteer editor too, click here.



Discuss in our Forums

See what other readers are saying about this article!

Click here to read & post comments.

53 posts so far.

Share this:
reddit this reddit thisbookmark with del.icio.us Del.icio.usdigg thisseed newsvineSeed NewsvineStumbleUpon StumbleUponsubmit to propellerkwoff it

About the Author

Alan Moran is the principle of Regulatory Economics.

Other articles by this Author

All articles by Alan Moran

Creative Commons LicenseThis work is licensed under a Creative Commons License.

Photo of Alan Moran
Article Tools
Comment 53 comments
Print Printable version
Subscribe Subscribe
Email Email a friend
Advertisement

About Us Search Discuss Feedback Legals Privacy